• We have updated our Community Code of Conduct. Please read through the new rules for the forum that are an integral part of Paradox Interactive’s User Agreement.

keynes2.0

Field Marshal
45 Badges
Jun 27, 2010
7.861
4.281
  • Crusader Kings II
  • Stellaris - Path to Destruction bundle
  • Rome: Vae Victis
  • Victoria 2: Heart of Darkness
  • Victoria 2: A House Divided
  • Rome Gold
  • Europa Universalis: Rome
  • Europa Universalis IV: Res Publica
  • March of the Eagles
  • Knights of Pen and Paper +1 Edition
  • Europa Universalis IV: Call to arms event
  • Europa Universalis IV: Wealth of Nations
  • Europa Universalis IV: Conquest of Paradise
  • Europa Universalis III: Chronicles
  • Hearts of Iron Anthology
  • Crusader Kings II: Charlemagne
  • Crusader Kings II: Legacy of Rome
  • Crusader Kings II: The Old Gods
  • Europa Universalis IV
  • Crusader Kings II: Rajas of India
  • Crusader Kings II: The Republic
  • Crusader Kings II: Sons of Abraham
  • Crusader Kings II: Sunset Invasion
  • Darkest Hour
  • East India Company
  • Age of Wonders: Planetfall
  • BATTLETECH: Season pass
  • Surviving Mars: First Colony Edition
  • BATTLETECH: Flashpoint
  • Surviving Mars: First Colony Edition
  • Age of Wonders II
  • Age of Wonders
  • BATTLETECH: Heavy Metal
  • Age of Wonders: Shadow Magic
  • Age of Wonders III
  • Surviving Mars
  • BATTLETECH
  • Hearts of Iron IV: Cadet
  • Stellaris Sign-up
  • Stellaris
  • Crusader Kings II: Conclave
  • Pride of Nations
  • 500k Club
  • Victoria 2
  • Cities: Skylines
I came across an interesting blog post today: https://growthecon.com/blog/When-Growth/

The author argues that economic history research suggests that in Western Europe wage growth starting around 1650 not late in the 19th century as is commonly held. This argument is based around the idea that previous studies of consumption made incorrect assumptions about amounts of compensated work and the type of compensation (we should pay less attention to money and more to in kind payments).

This strikes me as ideas that would drastically alter my understanding of history if true. It would suggest that the industrial revolution was not the thing that produced a virtuous economic cycle but was rather the product of a virtuous economic cycle already in progress. The 1600s simply do not have any remotely plausible mechanical inventions for an economic transformation like with the steam engine at the start of the 19th century. Perhaps economic growth was due to the availability of new crops? Perhaps better economics from the cultural changes in Europe at the time?

Some random thoughts of things that could relate:
Temin's research on the Roman empire suggests that there was a sustained increase in consumption during the Pax Romana until the crisis of the 3rd century. So this could be a repeated pattern of pre-mechanical societies having growth.
This would do away with the strange paradox of why western Europe was apparently so poor compared to China but still had enough surplus to make such massive expenditures.
It's frequently noted that social unrest doesn't come from people who have never known prosperity, it comes from people who knew prosperity then lost it. The american and french revolutions could fit into this paradigm if in fact the rise in living standards predated those revolutions not post-dated them.
The relative abundance of 17th century artifacts could be not just because they had less time to be lost but also because there was more handicrafts being made then in previous centuries.
If this hypothesis is true it could change the answer to the question "could ancient Rome or Tang China or whereever have started the industrial revolution?" It could be that they in fact were several centuries into the economic transition but were derailed.
 
Last edited:
This thesis is as far as I know generally accepted as the ‘correct’ one in all serious historical thought. Industrialization wasn’t some specific process or event that happen led to land willy nilly in some random spot. It took place gradually at a time and place after many other necessary events before then.

Ancient Rome probably wasn’t a good candidate for industrialization because it heavily relied very extensively on mass slavery to power its economy. China was, but lacked sufficiently large trade partners and exploitable external markets to make it worthwhile. Europe succeeded because the burst of wealth and productivity associated with the discovery of the new world and the ‘fortuitous’ population rebound from the previous Black Death created a situation with massive new markets for goods, and enormous new sources of raw materials at the same time the economy was already accelerating and creating a labor shortage to make handicraft production on a large scale. There were several centuries of hithertoo unheard of economic growth before it slowly morphed into what we now call the industrial revolution.

Basically like the tide coming in - economic success and wealth begat more success and wealth in ways previously unimaginable.
 
Can't access the site for some reason (browser gives some protocol/certificate error), so can't assess it. I can buy wage growth accompanying population declines (and there were population declines across most European countries in the 17th C.) but not sure what they're basing their extrapolations on.
 
Can't access the site for some reason (browser gives some protocol/certificate error), but not buying it. I can buy wage growth accompanying population declines (and there were population declines across most European countries in the 17th C.) but not sure what they're basing their extrapolations on.

Try a different browser for the https problem you have?

This research actually points at the increase in purchasing power post-plague being much smaller then previously thought. They are basing their extrapolations upon historical records of payments but with different calculations of the work period and more attention to payment in kind.
 
Try a different browser for the https problem you have?

No can do.

This research actually points at the increase in purchasing power post-plague being much smaller then previously thought. They are basing their extrapolations upon historical records of payments but with different calculations of the work period and more attention to payment in kind.

So they're just re-setting the base period and assume the rest? Sounds fishy.
 
No, they are recalculating the work year that was previously assumed.

Meaning what? Sorry to have to ask you second-hand. Is there paper link?
 
Doesn't seem impossible. One would expect better agricultural productivity from new crops. One would also expect wage rises from something like the Thirty Years War.

At the same time, said wage growth is probably going to be very small compared to what we think. Even in 1900 you're looking at a Europe that is largely still populated by peasant farmers. In 1700 I'd expect similar, even if there had been an increase in their prosperity.
 
My understanding is that the 18th century was fairly good economically: It was when a lot of new crops really started to kick in (along with continued organizational changes in the agricultural sector). Admittedly part of it is a rebound from the fairly disastrous 17th century.
 
This only concern England, and I question how universal a dating to the mid 17th century is when applied to the rest of mainland Europe, since England and the Netherlands diverged from the evolution of the rest of Europe. For example, I wouldn't be surprised if the Dutch situation began diverging during the earlier rise of the Dutch power. But what I'd really like to see is a comparison with Spain and France.
 
The question when did the economy reach the post Malthusian stage, that surplus production quickly converted into surplus population. The 1600s might work, but exporting surplus pop to the colonies distort the situation.
 
The question when did the economy reach the post Malthusian stage, that surplus production quickly converted into surplus population. The 1600s might work, but exporting surplus pop to the colonies distort the situation.

Suddenly gaining access to a massive new source of resources gets you out of the malthusian trap, at least until the population has expanded to fill the new source of land. The entire time period from 1600 to ~ 1900 represents Europe taking advantage of being temporarily 'freed' from the Malthusian trap thanks to massive immigration from Europe to the new world.
 
Last edited:
Suddenly gaining access to a massive new source of resources gets you out of the malthusian trap, at least until the population has expanded to fill the new source of land. The entire time period from 1600 to ~ 1900 represents Europe taking advantage of being temporarily 'freed' from the Malthusian trap thanks to massive immigration from Europe to the new world.

That's not really true, migration to the new world was fairly small from a total perspective until the 19th century. (though it did have some local influence in Britain)
 
The question when did the economy reach the post Malthusian stage, that surplus production quickly converted into surplus population. The 1600s might work, but exporting surplus pop to the colonies distort the situation.

Can such a small population flow matter that much? Serious question, I can believe there some reason why a small outlet would change the dynamic, I just can't imagine it.
 
That's not really true, migration to the new world was fairly small from a total perspective until the 19th century. (though it did have some local influence in Britain)

Can such a small population flow matter that much? Serious question, I can believe there some reason why a small outlet would change the dynamic, I just can't imagine it.

You don’t have to export your people to the new land in order to escape a Malthusian environment in the ‘homeland’. It’s perfectly sufficient to simply bring goods from the new lands that allow a greater subsistence and/or economic opportunities than would otherwise have existed. The introduction and eventual widespread cultivation of potatoes and corn did a great deal to increase the number of people who could live in Europe without risk of famine. So to did the discovery and exploitation of the Grand Banks fisheries.


Less directly the exploitation of massive stores of wealth did the same thing. Tiny numbers of Spaniards looting and mining vast treasures of gold and silver, tiny numbers of traders creating and enabling a network that stripped an entire continent bare of beaver furs, and the setup and exploitation of slave labor on a vast scale in the Caribbean to make sugar, tobacco and coffee were all ways to greatly increase the ability of the exploiting European powers to easily and effectively buy anything they might have run short of in ways that would have been inconceivable before such vast streams of wealth were made available to them.
 
Okay, if I understood correctly it was not through emmigration, but via improved crop yield and silver influx how Europe got a temporary relief from the Malthusian trap. Thanks.
 
The latter half of the 17th century saw increased investments in mechanizing mining although I don't recall any noticeable drop in metal prices.
 
You don’t have to export your people to the new land in order to escape a Malthusian environment in the ‘homeland’. It’s perfectly sufficient to simply bring goods from the new lands that allow a greater subsistence and/or economic opportunities than would otherwise have existed. The introduction and eventual widespread cultivation of potatoes and corn did a great deal to increase the number of people who could live in Europe without risk of famine. So to did the discovery and exploitation of the Grand Banks fisheries.

That's not "escaping" the Malthusian trap. That is the Malthusian trap. If more food generates more people, that is exactly what the trap is. You're dividing the greater food supply by a greater denominator, and thus nullifying the gain. You got tons more people - but each is as poor as before.

Potatoes is a perfect example, e.g. it generated a population explosion in Ireland. But the Irish poor were no richer as a consequence.

You can only "escape" from the Malthusian trap by not generating more people. Or getting rid of the extra population somehow. Killing them off in famines, pestilence & war is one way. Emigration is another way.

(You also can be more imaginative, e.g. institute "one child policies", lock the young up in celibate monasteries, sacrifice them en masse to Quetzalcoatl, etc. All helpful stuff. :D)